Totally agree. Have you listened to the other conversation in that post? it goes into a lot more detail. I think that this is basically the best argument for "mincome" or something like it. There are, in the not too distant future, going to be people who aren't just unemployed, they are unemployable. We will be in a "post-scarcity economy"
I know what I'm going to do tonight! Thanks for the link :) I, of course -- (I am not a monster!) -- I support Universal Basic Income (UBI). But I think the whole notion and societal conversation of a UBI suggests to me that there is something far more serious and fundamental that is wrong with our socioeconomic system (not that that is news...) and that we need to go beyond money, whatever, post-money, eventually. I think eventually it will be unnecessary and there will be a more effective and humane ways to build trust and collaboration between humans and the networks of AI/AGI that emerge throughout the century. Even sharing economy and gift economy models of organization are surprisingly varied and abundant, I have been looking more into different entities that function without money, and there are many of them! One of my favourite examples is, and I have used it quite a lot now, is couch surfing. It totally functions, it could of course function better, but it totally functions just on altruism and reputation systems, which enable a type of social trust without any money exchanging hands. I think there are signs for optimism here.Have you listened to the other conversation in that post? it goes into a lot more detail.
I think that this is basically the best argument for "mincome" or something like it. There are, in the not too distant future, going to be people who aren't just unemployed, they are unemployable. We will be in a "post-scarcity economy"
Do you really see money as the bad guy? Money is quite popular, and has enjoyed a high approval rating for some time. mk mentioned that paper showing that money is really just a form of credit. People ran with it, concluding that banks manufacture money out of thin air, but the real lesson is that all of us have that power. When I forget my wallet and borrow lunch money from a coworker, my IOU is "money" in just the same way. As is true of any powerful tool, money can lead to harm. (And is true of every good intention, trying to prevent such harms can lead to harm.) The sharing economy has advantages for shareable goods, and already functions alongside the money-based economy for consumable goods. What if I sleep on your couch today, with the understanding that you can sleep on my couch some other time? To the extent that our agreement is a real obligation, we have just created a kind of money. If we have friends in common who enjoy mutual trust, you could perhaps exchange your couch ticket for a meal or something else. If I want something, I can approach a complete stranger who is willing to provide it, almost anywhere in the world, and give them some colorful pieces of paper or their digital equivalent in exchange, and everybody walks away happy. What more effective and humane way to build trust and collaboration could be conceived?
In a recently published book that I'm currently reading, Other People's Money, the author (John Kay) makes the point that heavy regulation is actually a big part of the problem in the finance world. According to his analysis, most of what investment banks are engaged in these days is arbitrage, which take the form of fiscal, accounting, and regulatory. Essentially, he says that governments and investment banks are in an ever increasing arms race (JP Morgan for example employs tens of thousands of regulatory compliance officers) that ends up being very profitable for the banks at the expense of taxpayers and borrowers, as well as entrepreneurs who can't hope to keep up with tax codes that take 1000 people to read fully. Kay, although a "liberal" thinker by current popular definitions, suggests that much financial regulation needs to be scaled way back and modernized, and that "reform" is needed far more than regulation. Although I haven't reached his chapters on reform yet, so I'm not sure what he means by it exactly, I believe he is alluding to cultural biases toward making money at all other costs. He quibbles heavily with main stream economists' appropriation of the word 'rational' as only meaning "what makes the most money in the term we're currently concerned about."And is true of every good intention, trying to prevent such harms can lead to harm.
I have probably disagreed with you more than anyone else on the site, but now and then you say something with which I could not agree more. When we see social problems, it's common to expect government to make it better. That's their job, right? That may even be their intention, but intentions and results are two different things. Responsible regulators know that it is possible to mess things up by interfering. To tread carefully, they might seek advice before acting. Who do they seek advice from? The experts, of course: the largest, most-connected industry insiders. (Sometimes the regulator saves a step by being an industry insider.) Even if they do not seek advice, special interests have incentive to lobby for favorable legislation, while the negative effects are too broadly spread to attract organized dissent. The result, too often, is regulation that benefits the best-connected insider, at the expense of their competition, customers, taxpayers — everyone else. So when you suggest that we regulate marketing drugs, regulate wages, regulate real estate investment, regulate corporate finance, regulate Amazon, regulate farming, regulate legal financing, regulate horse shit, you may well be advocating for the entrenchment and perpetuation of these special interests and their unfair advantages.an ever increasing arms race ... that ends up being very profitable for the banks
Regulation or not, the thing we mainly need to keep in mind is outcome. I just had a conversation with mk earlier today about how frustrating it can be that NIH typically seems more concerned with mechanism than outcomes in what they choose to fund. Same applies to regulation. There can be good ones and bad ones, but what should define either isn't how "fair" the playing field is, but what the end product looks like. Imagining the world we would like to live in then thinking of ways we can make the world conform to that vision is a better strategy than ensuring rules are strictly adhered to.